Curb Your Car Coalition

A Community Conversation on Transportation in Tompkins County, NY

Curbing Parking:  Local zoning laws mandate parking spaces as if empty lots were a virtue

By Alan Ehrenhalt.  Published in Governing Magazine/June 2005

Also available freely online at http://www.governing.com/articles/6assess.htm


Here's a question for you: How many parking spaces should a convent be
legally required to provide?

If you immediately answered "zero," that's probably because you have some
common sense. Parking at a convent shouldn't be a zoning question. The
Mother Superior should be able to do whatever she wants. When there's a
problem, the nuns will tell her.

In fact, however, that's not the way it works in most American
cities. Convents usually have to have a minimum amount of parking to
stay within the law. So do at least 265 other kinds of enterprises,
including golf courses, zoos, sex shops, slaughterhouses, maternity
hospitals and taxi stands. All of them are on a list compiled by
Donald Shoup, an economics professor at UCLA, in a new book that is
undoubtedly the most comprehensive study of parking ever undertaken in
this country.

Shoup tells us, among other things, that the most common requirement for
convents is one space for every 10 nuns in residence. That may seem a
little arbitrary, but some of the others are worse. Taxi stands, for
example. I've never met anybody who drove to a taxi stand, parked, and
then hailed a cab. The average cabbie doesn't need parking either--he uses
one vehicle, and it's on the road during business hours. And yet most
cities not only require parking spaces at cab stands but also require a
fixed number: one space for each employee on the largest shift, plus one
for each taxi. Some zoning laws demand extra spaces for
"visitors"--whoever they might be.

Where do rules like this come from? In general, they come from a
document called "Parking Generation," which was first published
decades ago by the Institute of Transportation Engineers and has been
updated periodically since then. As Shoup puts it, local zoning officials
who consult Parking Generation "act like frightened supplicants bowing
before a powerful totem. ITE's stamp of authority relieves planners from
the obligation to think for themselves because simple answers are right
there in the book."

Unfortunately for convents, taxi stands and countless other
enterprises, the answers in the ITE book make very little sense. They tend
to be based on a percentage of maximum occupancy--that is, the largest
number of cars ever likely to use a facility at a given moment. The manual
recommends enough spaces to ensure that virtually every driver will be
able to find one virtually all the time. And then cities go ahead and
require those spaces as a matter of law.

Think how odd that is. If I were building a hotel, and I knew that I
could fill 200 rooms on the busiest day of the year, but only 50 on an
average day, I wouldn't build 200 and leave three-quarters of them empty
most nights. I wouldn't open a restaurant so big I couldn't fill it up
except on Valentine's Day and New Year's Eve. Neither would you. You'd
just accept it as a fact of life that once in a while, somebody will have
to be turned away.

It's only when it comes to parking lots that planners and local
governments insist on invoking a concept as foolish as maximum
capacity. And that's for a rather simple reason: When it comes to
parking, nobody worries about losing money. Parking, after all, is
free.

Or, rather, they think it's free. Of course, it isn't. That's the idea
that Shoup sets forth in abundant detail in his book, which he calls,
appropriately, "The High Cost of Free Parking." If I were to tell you a
733-page book about parking is a great read, you probably wouldn't believe
me. The fact is, however, that Mr. Shoup's opus not only is lucid and
convincing but also witty, erudite and highly enjoyable. It quotes Albert
Einstein and Robert Frost, Lewis Carroll and Graham Greene. It is filled
with quirky little details about the way ordinary people go about their
lives.

Most of all, however, it is filled with animosity toward free
parking. Shoup hates free parking--especially the off-street parking
that developers and businesses are required to provide in order to
operate. He says it degrades urban life in ways that hardly anybody
bothers to think about. "Because we never see the money we spend on
parking," he says, "it always seems someone else is paying for it...
but by prescribing massive overdoses of parking, planners are
poisoning the city."

How, exactly? Well, for one thing, parking lots eat up a huge amount of
land that could be used for more productive purposes. Many shopping malls
devote 60 percent of their surface land to parking spaces and only 40
percent to the buildings. For the most part, that's not because developers
insisted on all that parking. It's because zoning law forced them to
create it. Either way, the result is oceans of asphalt and an ugly
landscape as far as the eye can see.

All the land that's paved over and reserved for cars is land that
can't be used for housing--affordable or any other kind. Because
parking requirements have taken so much land out of development, they
force up the cost of building on whatever land remains. Rents are higher
than they would otherwise need to be. What's more, the parking
requirements written into zoning law make smaller, moderately priced
apartments difficult to produce anywhere.

Some cities in Southern California require residential developers to
provide as many as 3.25 spaces per apartment. That often leaves as
practical only two kinds of projects: a massive, sprawling condo complex
that meets the requirement by paving over additional acres of land, or a
boutique development that makes money by selling or renting luxury units
at luxury prices. A densely built project filled with compact two- and
three-bedroom apartments just doesn't cost out.

Meanwhile, in the central business districts of older cities, the
amount of parking keeps increasing and the number of buildings keeps
declining. Buffalo and Albuquerque devote more central-city land to
parking lots than to all other uses combined. For anyone who wants to come
downtown, a member of the Buffalo City Council lamented a couple of years
ago, "there will be lots of places to park. There just won't be a whole
lot to do here."

That's one of the simple ironies of this whole depressing subject.
But there's an even bigger irony: The central city districts that have
done really well in recent years aren't the ones that have provided the
most parking; they're the ones that have provided the least. Portland,
Oregon, instead of expanding its downtown parking capacity, has spent the
past 30 years restricting it. There was less parking per capita in
downtown Portland in the 1990s than there was in the 1970s. And Portland,
as any visitor notices at once, has one of the most successful downtowns
in America.

Los Angeles and San Francisco both opened new concert halls in the
1990s. Los Angeles included a six-level garage for 2,188 cars, built
at a cost of $110 million. San Francisco, on the other hand, put in no
garage--for a total cost of nothing. After each concert in L.A., the
patrons head straight for their cars, leaving the area around the building
deserted. After concerts in San Francisco, people spill out onto the local
streets, spending money in local bars, restaurants and bookstores. Some of
them have to walk several blocks to their cars parked along the curb, but
every block they walk adds extra life to the neighborhood.

How smart do cities have to be to learn the lessons of all this?
Smarter than most of them have been so far, apparently. But as cynical as
Shoup can sometimes sound, he has a few modest proposals for dealing with
the disasters of parking policy.

First, he suggests, instead of making developers build off-street
parking, allow them to pay a fee in lieu of each space provided. If
you make the fee less than the cost of building the space, most of
them will accept that deal. Some 25 American cities are actually doing
this. Most of them are small towns in California, or wealthy suburbs in
the east, but there are some surprises. Orlando, Florida, allows subsidies
in lieu of parking. So does Chapel Hill, North Carolina. The developers
get to spend more money on the actual project. And the fees go for public
improvement in the area.

Then, since the amount of parking will be reduced, allow commuters to
take the value of a free parking space in the office lot and trade it in
for cash. They can use it on public transportation, and if they don't
spend it all, they can keep what's left over. Different versions of this
experiment have been tried in Denver, Dallas, Salt Lake City and San Jose.
Ultimately, though, as Shoup himself concedes, there's a more basic
answer: Local governments have to rethink the whole idea of parking.
Even here, there's something to report. Minneapolis and Chicago are
now exempting the first 4,000 square feet of retail space in a new
development from any parking requirements at all. That's a tiny step, but
it's a step.

The asphalt jungle we have created will not disappear anytime soon.
As Shoup says, "automobile dependency resembles addiction to smoking, and
free parking is like free cigarettes...it will take decades for cities to
recover from the damage." That's a sobering thought. On the other hand, as
the Chinese would probably understand, sometimes even a journey of a
thousand miles has to start with a single parking space.Ironically, the
central city districts that have thrived in recent years aren't the ones
that have provided the most parking; they are the ones that have provided
the least.

----------------------------------------------------------------------

Copyright 2005, Congressional Quarterly, Inc. Reproduction in any form
without the written permission of the publisher is prohibited. Governing,
City & State and Governing.com are registered trademarks of Congressional
Quarterly, Inc. http://governing.com

Last updated Friday, February 3, 2006

Home  |  About CYCC  |  Meetings  |  Events  | News  |  Links  |  Safe Routes to School

For more information about CYCC or to become involved, contact David Kay